Existence of Equilibria in Financial Markets With Restricted


Participation1

Bernard Cornet2 and, Ramu Gopalan3

Abstract

It is well known that equilibrium asset prices will not offer arbitrage opportunities to individuals. Using an approach that dates back to Cass (1984) [4], we seek to isolate arbitrage free asset prices that are also equilibrium asset prices. However we do this when each agent’s portfolio choice is restricted to a closed, convex set containing zero (as in Siconolfi [27]). In the presence of such portfolio restrictions we need to confine our attention to aggregate arbitrage-free asset prices. We also describe a considerably weak condition on the space of income transfers(the union of the agents’ payoff sets is linear), that ensure these asset prices to be part of a financial equilibrium. We also show that weakning this condition further to require the union of the payoff set to be convex results only in a quasi-equilibrium. Staying in the Cass [4] framework, we consider an exchange economy with nominal assets, but allow for multiple (finite) periods and very general preference relations. Moreover we show the existence theorem using the approach of Martins Da-Rocha and Triki [8], and hence do not resort to the Cass trick.

Keywords: Exchange Economies, incomplete markets, financial equilibrium, constrained portfolios, multiperiod models, arbitrage free asset prices.

JEL Classification: C62, D52, D53, G11, G12.

1

Current version: October 2008 2

Paris School of Economics, Paris France and University of Kansas, Lawrence, KS 3

University of Texas at Dallas, Richardson, TX (ramu.gopalan@utdallas.edu)

1

Contents

  1. Introduction           3
  2. The T-period financial exchange economy   6
    1. Time and uncertainty in a multiperiod model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .   6
    2. The stochastic exchange economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .      7
    3. The financial structure      . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .        7
    4. Financial equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .  9
    5. Arbitrage and equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .            10
  3. Existence of equilibrium      11
    1. The main existence result . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .           11
    2. Other definitions of quasi-equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .      13
  4. Proof of existence under additional assumptions.    14
    1. Additional assumptions     . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .          14
    2. Preliminary lemma . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .   15
      1. The fixed point argument          . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .      15
      2. Properties of x,w,¯ p,¯ q¯). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
      3. Limit argument when  converges to zero and quasi-weak-

                          equilibrium.                    . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .                      21

    1. Proof in the general case (without additional assumptions) . . . . . . . . .        22
      1. Enlarging the preferences as in Gale and Mas-Colell . . . . . . . . .    23
      2. Truncating the economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .    24
  1. Appendix: Proof of lemma 4.2         26
  1. Introduction

In financial markets investors face several restrictions on what assets they can trade and the extent to which they can trade in these assets. For instance in September 2008, in the midst of the current financial crisis, short sales on several stocks were banned in UK. Similar actions were taken by the SEC in US a week later, when short sales in almost 800 stocks were banned for a couple of weeks. Such constraints on the investor’s portfolio choices are not exceptional cases. Even during peroids of normalcy there are several restrictions that investors face with respect to their asset market participation, apart from their own wealth constraints.

In general there are two reasons why such restrictions exist in financial markets - institutional or behavioral reasons. Some of the well known institutional restrictions are transactions costs, short sales constraints, margin requirements, frictions due to bid-ask spreads and taxes, collateral requirements, capital adequacy ratios and target rations. Elsinger and Summer [12] give a good discussion of these institutional constraints and how to model them in a general financial model. On the other hand investors may be restricted due to some behavioral reasons. For instance following Radner and Rothschild [25] we can suppose that agents have limits on the how much information they can process. This may cause each investor to concentrate on only a subset of assets to begin with.

Given that investors can face such restrictions on their portfolio choices, there are two ways in which such restrictions can be incorporated into a general financial model. The first is to assume that these restrictions are institutional and hence exogenously given. Then we can take them as primitives of the model. Alternatively, we can model them as arising engodenously. It is worth notiong that in a truly general model these constraints should be determined endogenously. Villanacci et al. [28] sumarize some of their work in this direction.

In this paper we adopt the view that these restrictions are institutional following the approach of Balasko, Cass and Siconolfi [2]. Moreover, we consider very general restrictions on portfolio sets as in Siconolfi [27], where each agent’s portfolio set is assumed to be closed, convex and contains zero. Such general portfolio set are able to capture all the institutional restrictions listed earlier (see [12]).

Investors primarily use financial assets to enable income transfers in order to achieve a consumption bundle that would maximize their preferences. With such investors, we need to address two important ideas that is relevant to economists - that of arbitrage and equilibrium. Such preference maximizing agents would be ready to seize any arbitrage opportunity that may arise in financial markets. However, if each investor faces different constraints on portfolios (there is good reason to believe that this is the case), then the arbitrage opportunities that open up to individuals will be different from one another and different from what may be available to the market as a whole. Hens et al. [18] show this distinction in a 2-date model with linear portfolio sets. Cornet and Gopalan [7] extend this result to a model with more than two dates. Also, since all agents will be choosing optimal consumptions and portfolios in an equilibrium, it is obvious that, with non-satiation, none of the agents will by themself find an arbitrage opportunity at equilibrium.

This paper primarily examines the existence of a financial equilibrium in a multiperiod model when investors face such general portfolio restrictions. In such models there are two possible ways to approach existence issue. One would be to directly show the existence of commodity and asset prices and commmodity and asset allocations which are optimal for all agents and all markets clear. The other approach, motivated by Cass ([4] and [5]), is to look for arbitrage-free asset prices that are also equilibrium asset prices.

In 2-date (one period) models without restrictions on portfolio sets, the existence issue has been extensively studied. Cass ([4]) and Werner ([29], [30]) showed existence with nominal assets. Duffie and Shafer ([11]) showed a generic existence result with real assets. This second approach has been extensively used. Magill and Shafer [19] provide a good survey of financial markets equilibria and contingent markets equilibria. Another approach to prove existence in a differentiable economy is to show existence in a numeraire asset economy and infer the existence in the nominal asset economy (See Villanacci et al. [28] and Magill and Quinzii [20]).

Multiperiod models are better equipped to capture the evolution of time and uncertainty and are a necessary step before studying infinite horizon models. Following Debreu’s [9] pioneering model we consider an event-tree to represent the evolution of time and uncertainty. Magill and Quinzii ([20]) and Angeloni and Cornet ([1]) are great references for the treatment of multiperiod financial models. Each node in the event tree represents a date-event. Given information on asset prices and spot prices at all nodes, consumers will choose a consumption and a portfolio of assets (assumed to be constrained here), such that the node specific value of the consumption does not exceed the node specific value of their endowments and the net returns from the portfolio.

In the absence of portfolio constraints, Cass ([4]), Duffie ([10]) and Florenzano and Gourdel ([13]) show the characterization of equilibrium and arbitrage free asset prices. In the presence of such constraints Cass ([4] and [5]) approached the existence problem by assuming that there is some agent who is unconstrainted. Then this agent would be able to accommodate the excess demands of all the other agents facilitating the existence proof. Around the same time Werner [29], Duffie and Shafer [11] and Magill and Shafer [19] provided similar approaches to show existence. This approach has been extensively used to show existence ever since, Florenzano and Gourdel ([13]), Magill and Quinzii ([20]), Angeloni and Cornet ([1]) among others.

This approach of assuming one agent to have unconstrained porfolio sets, breaks the symmetry of the problem and hence it is not possible to give a symmetric existence result (symmetric with respect to the agents’ problem). More recently in a working paper, with such general portfolio restrictions, Da-Rocha and Triki ([8]) have been able to show the characterization between equilibrium and arbitrage free asset prices without the use of the Cass approach.

In this paper we explore this characterization issue by showing that any aggregate arbitrage-free asset price can be supported as an equilibrium asset price. The approach here is similar to that in Da-Rocha and Triki ([8]), however the notion of absence of arbitrage and the assumptions on the set of income transfers are weaker. In this paper we show two kinds of results. If the cone formed by the union of all the agents portfolio sets is convex then any aggregate arbitrage-free asset price will also be a quasi-equilibrium asset price. However if this cone is linear then we can show that any market arbitrage-free asset price will be an equilibrium asset price.

Section 2 describes the T-period model and the notion of a financial equilibrium. Section 3, states the main result and discusses the different notions of equilibrium. Section 4 gives a detailed proof of the central result in this paper.

  1. The T-period financial exchange economy
    1. Time and uncertainty in a multiperiod model

We[1]consider a multiperiod exchange economy with (T + 1) dates, t ∈ T := {0,...,T}, and a finite set of agents I = {1,...,I}. The stochastic structure of the model is described by a finite event-tree D = {0,1,2,...,D} of length T and we shall essentially use the same model as Angeloni and Cornet [1], (we refer to [20] for an equivalent presentation with information partitions). The set Dt denotes the nodes (also called date-events) that could occur at date t and the family (Dt)t∈T defines a partition of the set D; for each ξ ∈ D we denote by t(ξ) the unique t ∈ T such that ξ ∈ Dt.

At each date t 6= T, there is an a priori uncertainty about which node will prevail in the next date. There is a unique non-stochastic event occurring at date t = 0, which is denoted ξ0, (or simply 0) so D0 = {ξ0} . Finally, every ξ ∈ Dt,t 6= 0 has a unique immediate predecessor in Dt−1, denoted pr(ξ). The predecessor mapping pr : D \ {ξ0} −→ D is assumed to satisfy pr(Dt) = Dt−1, for every t 6= 0. The element pr(ξ) is called the immediate predecessor of ξ and is also denoted ξ. For each ξ ∈ D, we let ξ+ = {ξ¯∈ D : ξ = ξ¯} be the set of immediate successors of ξ; we notice that the set ξ+ is nonempty if and only if ξ ∈ D \ DT .

Moreover, for τ ∈ T \ {0} and we define, by induction, prτ(ξ) = pr(prτ−1(ξ)) and we let the set of (not necessarily immediate) successors and the set of predecessors of ξ be respectively defined by

D+(ξ) = {ξ0 ∈ D : ∃τ ∈ T \ {0} | ξ = prτ(ξ0)},

D(ξ) = {ξ0 ∈ D : ∃τ ∈ T \ {0} | ξ0 = prτ(ξ)}.

If ξ0 ∈ D+(ξ) [resp. ξ0 ∈ D+(ξ) ∪ {ξ}], we shall also use the notation ξ0 > ξ [resp. ξ0 ξ].

We notice that D+(ξ) is nonempty if and only if ξ 6∈ DT and D(ξ) is nonempty if and only if ξ 6= ξ0. Moreover, one has ξ0 ∈ D+(ξ) if and only if ξ ∈ D(ξ0) and similarly ξ0 ξ+ if and only if ξ = (ξ0).

    1. The stochastic exchange economy

At each node ξ ∈ D, there is a spot market where a finite set H = {1,...,H} of divisible physical goods is available. We assume that each good does not last for more than one period. In this model, a commodity is a couple (h,ξ) of a physical good h ∈ H and a node ξ ∈ D at which it will be available, so the commodity space is RL, where L = H×D. An element x in RL is called a consumption, that is x = (x(ξ))ξ∈D RL, where x(ξ) = (x(h,ξ))h∈H RH, for every ξ ∈ D.

We denote by p = (p(ξ))ξ∈D RL the vector of spot prices and p(ξ) = (p(h,ξ))h∈H RH is called the spot price at node ξ ∈ D. The spot price p(h,ξ) is the price paid, at date t(ξ), for the delivery of one unit of the physical good h at node ξ. Thus the value of the consumption x(ξ) at node ξ ∈ D (evaluated in unit of account of node ξ) is

p(ξ) •H x(ξ) = X p(h,ξ)x(h,ξ).

h∈H

Each agent i ∈ I is endowed with a consumption set Xi RL which is the set of her possible consumptions. An allocation is an element x = (xi)i∈I Qi∈I Xi, where xi Xi denotes the consumption of agent i ∈ I.

The tastes of each consumer i ∈ I are represented by a strict preference correspondence Pi : Qj∈I Xj −→ Xi, where Pi(x) defines the set of consumptions that are strictly preferred by i to xi, that is, given the consumptions xj for the other consumers j 6= i. Thus Pi represents the tastes of consumer i but also her behavior under time and uncertainty, in particular her impatience and her attitude towards risk. If consumers’preferences are represented by utility functions ui : Xi −→ R, for every i ∈ I, the strict preference correspondence is defined by Pi(x) = {x¯i Xi | uixi)> ui(xi)}.

Finally, at each node ξ ∈ D, every consumer i ∈ I has a node-endowment ei(ξ) ∈ RH (contingent to the fact that ξ prevails) and we denote by ei = (ei(ξ))ξ∈D RL her endowment vector across the different nodes. The exchange economy E can thus be summarized by

E = [D;H;I;(Xi,Pi,ei)i∈I].

    1. The financial structure

We consider finitely many financial assets and we denote by J = {1,...,J} the set of assets. An asset j ∈ J is a contract, which is issued at a given and unique node in D, denoted by ξ(j) and called the emission node of j. Each asset j is bought (or sold) at its emission node ξ(j) and only yields payoffs at the successor nodes ξ0 of ξ(j), that is, for ξ0 > ξ(j). We denote by v(ξ,j) the payoff of asset j at node ξ. Since we consider only nominal assets this payoff does not depend on the spot prices. For the sake of convenient notations, we shall in fact consider the payoff of asset j at every node ξ ∈ D and assume that it is zero if ξ is not a successor of the emission node ξ(j). Formally, we assume that v(ξ,j) is defined for all nodes ξ ∈ D and that v(ξ,j) = 0 if ξ ∈ D6 +(ξ(j)). With the above convention, we notice that every asset has a zero payoff at the initial node, that is v(ξ0,j) = 0 for every j ∈ J . Furthermore, every asset j which is emitted at the terminal date T has a zero payoff, that is, if ξ(j) ∈ DT , v(ξ,j) = 0 for every ξ ∈ D.

For every consumer i ∈ I, if zij > 0 [resp. zij < 0], then |zij| will denote the quantity of asset j ∈ J bought [resp. sold] by agent i at the emission node ξ(j). The vector zi = (zij)j∈J RJ is called the portfolio of agent i.

The price of asset j is denoted by qj and we recall that it is paid at its emission node ξ(j). We let q = (qj)j∈J RJ be the asset price (vector).

We assume that each consumer i ∈ I is endowed with a portfolio set Zi RJ, which represents the set of portfolios that are admissible for agent i. If some agent i ∈ I has no constraints on her portfolio choices then Zi = RJ. In this paper we consider portfolio sets that closed, convex and contain zero for every agent.

To summarize, the financial asset structure F = (J,(ξ(j),V j)j∈J ,(Zi)i∈I) consists of

  • A finite set of assets J , and each asset j ∈ J is defined by its node of issue ξ(j) ∈ D and its payoff vector V j = (v(ξ,j))ξD RD, with v(ξ,j) = 0 if ξ /∈ D+.
  • The portfolio set Zi RJ for every agent i ∈ I.
  • The payoff matrix of F is the D × J matrix V = (v(ξ,j))ξ∈D,j∈J The full payoff matrix WF(q) is the (D × J)−matrix with entries

wF(q)(ξ,j) := v(ξ,j) − δξ,ξ(j)qj,

where δξ,ξ0 = 1 if ξ = ξ0 and δξ,ξ0 = 0 otherwise.

So for a given portfolio z RJ (and asset price q) the full flow of payoffs across all nodes is WF(q)z, a vector in RD whose ξ-th component is the (full) financial payoff at node ξ, that is

[WF(q)z](ξ) := WF(q,ξ) •J z = X v(ξ,j)zj X δξ,ξ(j)qjzj

                                                                           j∈J                               j∈J

                                            =              X                v(ξ,j)zj −                 X               qjzj.

                                                  {j∈J| ξ(j)}                                   {j∈J| ξ(j)=ξ}

We shall extensively use the fact that, for λ RD, and j ∈ J , one has:

[tWF(q)λ](j) = X λ(ξ)v(ξ,j) − X λ(ξ)δξ,ξ(j)

                                                            ξ∈D                                  ξ∈D

(2.1)                                                       = X λ(ξ)v(ξ,j) − λ(ξ(j))qj.

ξ>ξ(j)

In the following, when the financial structure F remains fixed, while only prices vary, we shall simply denote by W(q)the full payoff matrix. In the case of unconstrained portfolios, namely Zi = RJ, for every i ∈ I, the financial asset structure will be simply denoted by F = (J,(ξ(j),V j)j∈J ).

    1. Financial equilibrium

We now consider a financial exchange economy, which is defined as the couple of an exchange economy E and a financial structure F. It can thus be summarized by

(E,F) := [D,H,I,(Xi,Pi,ei)i∈I;J,(ξ(j),V j)j∈J ,(Zi)i∈I].

Given the price (p,q) ∈ RL × RJ, the budget set (resp. quasi-budget set) of consumer i ∈ I is5

Bi(p,q) = {(xi,zi) ∈ Xi × Zi : ∀ξ ∈ D, p(ξ) •H [xi(ξ) − ei(ξ)] ≤ [WF(q)zi](ξ)}

= {(xi,zi) ∈ Xi × Zi : p  (xi ei) ≤ WF(q)zi}.

resp. B˘i(p,q) = {(xi,zi) ∈ Xi × Zi : p  (xi eiWF(q)zi}.

When F is fixed we can drop the subscript F from the budget set. We now introduce the equilibrium notion.

Definition 2.1 (i) A financial accounts clearing equilibrium is a list of strategies and prices x, of the financial exchange economy (E,F) if p¯ 6= 0 and

(with x(ξ),p(ξ) in RH) we let p  x = (p(ξ)•Hx(ξ))ξ∈D

  1. for every i ∈ I,xi,z¯i) ∈ Bip,q¯) and [Pix) × Zi] ∩ Bip,q¯) = ∅;
  2. Xx¯i = Xei and XW¯ q)zi = 0.

i∈I

(ii) The listis a financial accounts clearing quasi-

equilibrium of the financial exchange economy (E,F) if p¯ 6= 0, (b) holds and

(ai) for every i ∈ I,xi,z¯i) ∈ Bip,q¯);

(aii) B˘ip,q¯) = ∅ and/or [Pix) × Zi] ∩ B˘ip,q¯) = ∅;

(a iii) for every ξ ∈ D \ D0,(xi(−s),xi(s)) ∈ Pix) implies p¯(s) •H (xi(s)) ≥ p¯(s) •H xi(s));

Remark 2.1 The above definition requires the balancing of accounts (or payoffs), that is P Wqzi = 0 instead of the balancing of portfolios, Pi∈Iz¯i = 0 which is needed in i∈I

the standard definition of equilibrium (see Magill and Quinzii).

Remark 2.2 If in addition we assume the following condition due to Martins da-Rocha and Triki [8],

                      (WEQ)                          − XZi Ker Wq) ⊂ X(A(Zi) ∩ Ker Wq)),

                                              i∈I                                                i∈I

then existence of the above defined accounts clearing equilibrium will imply the existence of an equilibrium in the usual sense where we have asset market clearing in portfolios that is Pi∈Iz¯i = 0.

    1. Arbitrage and equilibrium

In the case where portfolio sets are constrained, the absence of arbitrage opportunities at the individual level will differ from that at the aggregate level. As outlined in Angeloni and Cornet [1] we have the following definition.

Definition 2.2 Given the financial structure F = (J,(ξ(j),V j)j∈J ,(Zi)i∈I), a portfolio z¯i Zi is said to have no arbitrage opportunities or to be arbitrage-free for agent i ∈ I at the price q RJ if there is no portfolio zi Zi such that WF(q)zi > WF(qzi, that is, [WF(q)zi](ξ) ≥ [WF(qzi](ξ), for every ξ ∈ D, with at least one strict inequality, or, equivalently, if

.

When asset market participation is restricted, as we will show in the course of this paper, there are fewer asset prices that can be supported as equilibrium asset prices than those that do not offer arbitrage. We will thus consider a subset of the arbitrage-free asset prices that are given by the following definition.

Definition 2.3 We say that the asset price q is aggregate arbitrage-free if one of the following equivalent conditions hold [2]

.

(ii) There exists such that λ D w = 0 for all.

Consider the following non-satiation assumption:

Assumption NS (i) For every x¯ ∈ Qi∈I Xi such that Pi∈I x¯i = Pi∈I ei,

(Non-Satiation at Every Node) for every ξi ∈ D, there exists x Qi∈I Xi such that, for each ξ 6= ξi, xi(ξ) = ¯xi(ξ) and xi Pix); (ii) if xi Pix), then [xi,x¯i[⊂ Pix).

It is well known that if preferences are non-satiated then there is no arbitrage at the individual level. In particular, under (NS), if x,z,¯ p,¯ q¯) is an equilibrium of the economy (E,F), then z¯i is arbitrage-free at q¯for every i ∈ I (see Angeloni and Cornet [1]).

  1. Existence of equilibrium
    1. The main existence result

We will prove that when agents’ portfolio sets are constrained, any aggregate strong-noarbitrage asset price can be characterized as an equilibrium asset price. Our approach however does not cover the general case of real assets which needs a different treatment. Let us consider, the financial economy

(E,F) = [D,H,I,(Xi,Pi,ei)i∈I;J,(ξ(j),V j)j∈J ,(Zi)i∈I].

Define the set of attainable consumptions by

and for each be the projection of Xb on Xi.

We introduce the following assumptions.

Assumption (C) (Consumption Side) For all i ∈ I and all x¯ ∈ Qi∈I Xi,

  1. Xi RL is closed, convex and bounded below by xi.
  2. [Continuity] the preference correspondence Pi : Qi∈I Xi Xi, is lower semicontinuous[3]and Pix) is open in Xi (for its relative topology);
  3. [Convexity] Pix) is convex;
  4. (Irreflexivity) x¯i 6∈ Pix);
  5. (Non-Satiation of Preferences at Every Node) if Pi∈I x¯i = Pi∈I ei, for every ξ ∈ D there exists x Qi∈I Xi such that, for each ξ0 6= ξ, xi(ξ0) = ¯xi(ξ0) and xi Pix);
  6. (Survival Assumption) For all i ∈ I, ei Xi.

Note that these assumptions on Pi are satisfied in particular when agents preferences are given by a utility function that is continuous, monotonic increasing, and quasi-concave. Assumption (F) (Financial Side)

(i) For every i ∈ I, Zi is closed, convex and contains zero;

(iii) For every asset price q RJ, for every i ∈ I, W(q)Zi is a closed subset of RD;

We can now state the main theorem characterizing equilibrium prices with arbitrage free prices under the appropriate compatibility condition.

Theorem 3.1 (a) Suppose the financial exchange economy (E,F) satisfies C and F. Let q¯ ∈ RJ be an aggregate arbitrage-free asset price such that the following condition holds

(i) Closed Cone  is convex.

Then there exists x,z,¯ p¯) with p¯ 6= 0, such that x,z,¯ p,¯ q¯) is a financial accounts clearing quasiequilibrium.

(b) If we additionally assume that

(ii) Closed Cone  is linear,

then there exists x,z,¯ p¯) with p¯(ξ) 6= 0, for all ξ D such that x,z,¯ p,¯ q¯) is a financial accounts clearing equilibrium.

It is worth noticing that (WEQ) and (i) in the Theorem are satisfied in the following examples.

Example 3.1 For every i ∈ I,Zi is closed, convex and contains zero and Si∈IZi is a vector space. Consider for example, I = I1 ∪ I2 and

                                       i ∈ I1,                Zi = {z | z · e1 ≥ 0,e1 = (1,0)}

                                      i ∈ I2,                Zi = {z | z · e2 ≥ 0,e2 = (0,1)}.

That is every agent in I1 can buy the first asset and every agent in I2 can sell the first asset.

Example 3.2 (Cass Condition) For every i ∈ I,Zi is closed, convex and contains zero and for some i0 ∈ I,Zi Zi0 and Zi0 is a vector space. Then Si∈IZi = Zi0 is a vector space and we are in the structure of Example 3.1.

It is also worth noticing that in Condition (i) in Theorem 3.1, taking Si∈IWq)Zi to be ‘closed cone’ instead of a linear space allows us to consider the following example. Let

I = 1,2 and

Z1 = {z R2 | z2 ≥ (z1)2}

Z1 = {z R2 | z2 ≤ −(z1)2}

    1. Other definitions of quasi-equilibrium

Gottardi and Hens consider a two date incomplete markets model without consumption in the first date. Their definition of a quasi-equilibrium, suitably modified by Seghir et al. to include consumption in first date is presented below.

Definition 3.1 A list of strategies and prices x, is a quasiequilibrium of the financial exchange economy (E,F), if p¯ 6= 0,

(a i) for every i ∈ I,xi Pix) and p¯ 1(xi ei) ≤ V zi p¯(0)•H(xi(0)−ei(0))+¯qJzi ≥ 0;

(a ii) for every i ∈ I,p¯ (¯xi ei) = Wqzi;

(a iii) for every ξ ∈ D \ D0,(xi(−s),xi(s)) ∈ Pix) implies p¯(s) •H (xi(s)) ≥ p¯(s) •H xi(s));

(b) Xx¯i = Xei and Xz¯i = 0.

      i∈I                i∈I                   i∈I

Let

Bei(p,q) = {(xi,zi) ∈ Xi × Zi | p(0) •H (xi(0) − ei(0)) < q J zi;p  1(xi ei) ≤ V zi}

Notice that (a i) of this definition is true if an only if .

Comparing Definitions 2.1 and 3.1 we see that the quasi-equilibrium conditions a( ii), (a iii) and (b) are the same. The lemma that follows shows that in a two date model, a quasiweak-equilibrium in our model implies a quasi-weak-equilibrium in the sense of Seghir et al. In particular we show how (a i) in Definition 2.1 is related to (a i) of Definition 3.1.

Lemma 3.1 Under the assumption[4](F0): ζi A (Zi) such that V ζi >> 0,

(Pix) × Zi) ∩ B˘ip,q¯) = ∅ ⇒ (Pix) × Zi) ∩ Beip,q¯) = ∅.

Proof of Lemma 3.1. Suppose on the contrary there is some (xi,zi) ∈ (Pix) × Zi) ∩

Beip,q¯) 6= ∅. Then

p¯(0) •H (xi(0) − ei(0)) < q¯•J zi

p  1(xi ei) ≤ V zi.

Take ζi AZi with V ζi >> 0. Then for all t > 0 small enough

p¯(0) •H (xi(0) − ei(0)) < q¯•J zi q¯•J (i) = −q¯(z + i)

p  1(xi ei) << V (zi + i)

and clearly zi + i Zi since ζi AZi. This contradicts (Pix) × Zi) ∩ B˘ip,q¯) = ∅.

  1. Proof of existence under additional assumptions.
    1. Additional assumptions

We will first provide a proof of Theorem 3.1 under the following additional assumptions (together with those already made in Theorem 3.1).

Assumption K:

(i) The sets Xi and Wq)Zi for a given q¯∈ RJ, are bounded;

(ii)[Local Non-Satiation] for every x¯ ∈ Qi∈I Xi, for every xi Pix), [xi,x¯i) ⊂ Pix).

(iii) [Strong survival assumption] For every i ∈ I ei ∈ int Xi.

Then in the next section we will give the proof of Theorem 3.1 in the general case, that is without assuming Assumption K.

    1. Preliminary lemma

Before entering the proof of Theorem 3.1 we will state and prove the following:

Lemma 4.1 Let q¯∈ RJ, let W be a the closed convex cone then the following are equivalent:

.

(ii) There exists such that:

hWi ⊂ λ:= {t RD | λ D t = 0}.

The proof of Lemma 4.1 is standard (see Magill-Quinzii). In the following we let

W = closed convex cone (Wq)(∪IIZi)).

Let 9 BL = {p RL | ||λ  p|| ≤ 1}. Given as in Lemma 4.1, for each p ∈ BL let

ρ(p) = (ρ(p,ξ))ξ∈D RD with ρ(p,ξ) = 1 − ||λ  p|| for all ξ D.

Given p BL and a function γ : BL RD, for all i ∈ I define

Biγρ(p) = n(xi,wi) ∈ Xi × WZi : ∃τi ∈ [0,1],p(xi ei) ≤ wi + τiγ(p) + ρ(p)o,

B˘iγρ(p) = n(xi,wi) ∈ Xi × WZi : ∃τi ∈ [0,1],p(xi eiwi + τiγ(p) + ρ(p)o.

We state a lemma, which extends a previous result by Da-Rocha and Triki [8], the proof of which is given in the Appendix.

Lemma 4.2        (i) For every ε > 0, there exists a continuous mapping γ : BL RD such that, p BLD γ(p) = 0 and w ∈ W, w D γ(p) ≤ 0 and ||γ(p)|| ≤ ε.

(ii) Assume that the closed cone spanned by Wq)(∪IIZi) is convex, then p BL,i ∈ I, such that iγρ(p) 6= ∅ .

      1. The fixed point argument

Let γ : BL RD be the continuous mapping associated by Lemma 4.2 to some ε. For

(x,w,p) ∈ Qi∈I Xi × Qi∈I WZi × BL, we define the correspondences Φi for i ∈ I0 := {0} ∪ I as follows:

Φ0(x,w,p) = np0 BL | λ  (p0 p)L X(xi ei) > 0o,

i∈I

denotes the euclidean norm.

and for every i ∈ I,

                                                                             if (xi,wi) ∈ Biγρ(p) and B˘iγρ(p) = ∅,

            Φi(x,w,p) =         Biγρ(p)                                                if (xi,wi) ∈ B/ iγρ(p) and B˘iγρ(p) 6= ∅,

                                )                            if (xi,wi) ∈ Biγρ(p).

The existence proof relies on the following fixed-point-type theorem due to Gale and MasCollel ([15]).

Theorem 4.1 Let I0 be a finite set, let Ci (i ∈ I0) be a nonempty, compact, convex subset of some Euclidean space, let C = Qi∈I0 Ci and let Φi (i ∈ I0) be a correspondence from C to Ci, which is lower semicontinuous and convex-valued. Then, there exists c¯ ∈ C such that, for every i ∈ I0 either c¯i ∈ Φic) or Φic) = ∅.

We now show the sets C0 = BL, Ci = Xi ×WZi (i ∈ I) and the above defined correspondences Φi (i ∈ I0) satisfy the assumptions of Theorem 4.1.

Claim 4.1 For every c¯:= (¯x,w,¯ p,¯ ) ∈ Qi∈I Xi × Qi∈I WZi × BL,

  1. Φic) is convex (possibly empty);
  2. p¯ 6∈ Φ0c), and for all i ∈ I,xi,w¯i) ∈6 Φic);
  3. for every i ∈ I0, the correspondence Φi is lower semicontinuous at c¯.

Proof of Claim 4.1: Let c¯:= (¯x,w,¯ p¯) ∈ Qi∈I Xi × Qi∈I WZi × BL be given.

Proof of (i): Clearly Φ0c) is convex. For every i ∈ I, recalling that Pix) and WZi are convex sets, by Assumption C and F, we have Φic) is a convex set.

Proof of (ii): Clearly, p¯ 6∈ Φ0c) and xi,w¯i) 6∈ Φic) follows from the d efinitions of these sets and the fact that x¯i ∈6 Pix) (from Assumption C).

Proof of (iii): We need to show that Φi is lower semicontinuous for all i I0. Since Φ0 has an open graph, clearly it is lower semicontinuous. To show lower semicontinuity of Φi for i ∈ I, let U be an open subset of Xi × WZi such that Φ(¯c) ∩ U =6 ∅ and we will distinguish three cases:

Case(1): xi,w¯i) ∈ B/ iγρp) and iγρp) = ∅. Then Φic) = {(ei,0)} ⊂ U. The set i = {(xi,wi,p) | (xi,wi) ∈ B/ iγρ(p)} is an open subset of Xi × WZi × BL (by Assumptions C and F). To see this, let {(xi,wi,p)} be such that (xi,wi) ∈ Biγρ(p) and (xi,wi,p) → (x,w,p). Since for all n,(xi,wi) ∈ Biγρ(p), there exists τi ∈ [0,1] such that

p  (xi ei) ≤ wi + τiγ(p) + ρ(p)

In the limit we have

p  (x ei) ≤ w + τγ(p) + ρ(p)

Where τ = limn→∞τi ∈ [0,1]. Thus (x,w) ∈ Biγρ(p).

Thus i contains an open neighborhood O of c¯. Now, let c = (x,w,p) ∈ O. If B˘iγρ(p) = ∅ then Φi(c) = {(ei,0)} ⊂ U and so Φi(c)∩U is nonempty. If iγρ(p) 6= ∅ then Φi(c) = Biγρ(p).

But Assumptions C and F imply that (ei,0) ∈ Xi×WZi, hence  (with τi = 0 and noticing that ρ(p) ≥ 0). So {(ei,0)} ⊂ Φi(c) ∩ U which is also nonempty.

Case (2): c¯ = (¯xi,w¯i,p¯) ∈ Ωi := {c = (xi,wi,p) : (xi,wi) ∈ B/ iγρ(p) and iγρ(p) =6 ∅}. Then the set i is clearly open (since its complement is closed).

On the set i one has Φi(c) = Biγρ(p). We recall that ∅ 6= Φic)∩U = Biγρp)∩U. We notice that Biγρp) = cl B˘iγρp) since B˘iγρp) 6= ∅. Consequently, B˘iγρp) ∩ U 6= ∅ and we chose a point (xi,wi) ∈ B˘iγρp) ∩ U, that is, (xi,wi) ∈ [Xi × WZi] ∩ U and for some τi ∈ [0,1],

p¯ (xi eiwi + τiγp) + ρp).

Clearly the above inequality is also satisfied for the same point (xi,wi) and the same τi when p belongs to a neighborhood O of p¯ small enough (using the continuity of ρ(·) and γ(·)). This shows that on O one has ∅ 6= B˘iγρ(p) ∩ U ⊂ Biγρ(p) ∩ U = Φ(c) ∩ U.

Case (3): xi,w¯i) ∈ Biγρp). By assumption we have

∅ 6= Φic) ∩ U = B˘iγρp) ∩ [Pix) × WZi] ∩ U.

By an argument similar to what is done above, one shows that there exists an open neighborhood N of p¯and an open set M such that, for every p N, one has ∅ 6= M ⊂ B˘iγρ(p)∩U. Since Pi is lower semicontinuous at c¯ (by Assumption C, there exists an open neighborhood of c¯such that, for every c ∈ Ω, ∅ 6= [Pi(x) × WZi] ∩ M, hence

 for every c ∈ Ω.

Consequently, from the definition of Φi, we get ∅ 6= Φi(c) ∩ U, for every c ∈ Ω.

The correspondence Ψi := B˘iγρ ∩ (Pi × WZi) is lower semicontinuous on the whole set, being the intersection of an open graph correspondence and a lower semicontinuous correspondence. Then there exists an open neighborhood O of c¯ := (¯x,w,¯ p¯) such that, for every (x,w,p) ∈ O, then U ∩ Ψi(x,w,p) 6= ∅ hence ∅ 6= U ∩ Φi(x,w,p) (since we always have Ψi(x,w,p) ⊂ Φi(x,w,p)).

Given ε > 0, in view of Claim 4.1, we can apply the fixed-point Theorem 4.1. Thus there exists c¯= (¯x,w,¯ p¯) ∈ Qi∈I Xi ×Qi∈I WZi ×BL such that, for every i ∈ I0,Φix,w,¯ p¯) = ∅.

Written coordinatewise, this is equivalent to saying that:

(4.1)                           p BL, (λ  p) •D Xxi ei) ≤ (λ  p¯) •D Xxi ei)

                                                           i∈I                                                       i∈I

(4.2)                     i ∈ I,xi,w¯i) ∈ Biγρp) and iγρp) ∩ (Pix) × WZi) = ∅.

      1. Properties of x,w,¯ p,¯ q¯).

We first prove that x¯ = (¯xi)i∈I satifies the market clearing condition.

Claim 4.2 Pi∈Ix¯i = Pi∈Iei.

Proof of Claim 4.2: Suppose Pi∈Ixi ei) 6= 0. From the fixed-point assertion (4.1) we

P deduce that (λ                 and ||λ  p¯|| = 1. So

(4.3)p¯) •L Xxi ei) > 0.

i∈I

Recalling that xi,w¯i) ∈ Biγρp), for all i ∈ I, by the fixed-point assertion (4.2), hence there exists τ¯i ∈ [0,1] such that

p¯ (¯xi ei) ≤ w¯i + ¯τiγp) + ρp).

Summing up over i we get:

p¯Xxi ei) ≤ Xw¯i + (Xτ¯i)γp) + (#I)ρp).

                                      i∈I                              i∈I                  i∈I

Taking the scalar product with λ we get,

(λ  p¯) •L Xxi ei) ≤ λ D Xw¯i + (Xτ¯i)λ D γp) + (#I)λ D ρp).

                               i∈I                                          i∈I                  i∈I

On the right hand side, we have λ D Pi∈Iw¯i = 0 (by Lemma 4.1), λ D γp) = 0 (by Lemma 4.2), and ρp) = 0 (since ||λ  p¯|| = 1). Thus (λ  p¯) •L Pi∈Ixi ei) ≤ 0, which contradicts (4.3).

Claim 4.3 The following conditions hold:

  1. If for some i ∈ I, iγρp) 6= ∅ then xi,w¯i) ∈ Biγρp) and Biγρp) ∩ (Pix) × WZi) = ∅;
  2. For all;
  3. For all i ∈ I,xi,w¯i) ∈ Biγρp) and Biγρp) ∩ (Pixi) × WZi) = ∅.

Proof of Claim 4.3: Proof of (i): The first assertion that xi,w¯i) ∈ Biγρp) is a consequence of the Fixed-Point Assertion (4.2). We now show that Biγρp)∩(PixiWZi) = ∅. Indeed suppose that contains an element (xi,wi). Since, we

let xi,w¯i) ∈ B˘iγρp).

Suppose first that x¯i = xi, then, from above (xi,w¯i) ∈ [Pix) × WZi] ∩ B˘iγρp), which contradicts the fact that this set is empty by Assertion (4.2). Suppose now that x¯i 6= xi, from Assumption C (iii), (recalling that xi Pix)) the set xi,xi[∩Pix) is nonempty, hence contains a point xi(λ) := (1 − λxi + λxi for some λ ∈ [0,1[. We let wi(λ) := (1 − λ) ¯wi+ λwi and we check that (xi(λ),wi(λ)) ∈ B˘iγρp) (since (xi,wi) ∈ Biγρp) and xi,w¯i) ∈ B˘iγρp)). Consequently, B˘iγρp) ∩ (Pix) × WZi) =6 ∅, which contradicts again Assertion (4.2).

Thus

(4.4)                           xi,w¯i) ∈ Biγρp) and Biγρp) ∩ (Pix) × WZi) = ∅

Proof of (ii): From Lemma 4.2 (ii), there exists i0 ∈ I such that. Suppose there exists ξ ∈ D such that p(ξ) = 0. From Claim 4.2, Pi∈Ix¯i = Pi∈Iei, and from the Non-Satiation Assumption at node ξ (for Consumer i0) there exists xi0 Pi0x) such that

        0                                            0                                                            0

xi0(ξ ) = ¯xi0(ξ ) for every ξ 6= ξ; from Assertion (4.2),and, recalling that p¯(ξ) = 0, one deduces that . Consequently,

,

which contradicts Condition 4.4.

Proof of (iii): From Part (ii) of this Claim we have, for all, hence

p¯(ξ) · p¯(ξ) > 0 and p  p >>¯ 0. Taking w¯i = 0¯i = 0 and x¯i = ei tp¯, for t > 0 small enough, we get x¯i BL(ei,r) ⊂ Xi (from the Survival Assumption). Then p¯ (¯xi ei) = −tp  p¯)  0 ≤ 0 + ρp). This shows that (xi,0) ∈ B˘iγρp) =6 ∅.

Claim 4.4 The following conditions hold:

  1. ρp) = 0
  2. If closed cone  is linear then for all i ∈ I¯iγp) = 0 and Pi∈Iw¯i = 0.
  3. If closed cone  is convex then ||Pi∈Iw¯i|| ≤ (#I)||γp)||.

Proof of Claim 4.4: Proof of (i): We first prove that the modified budget constraints are binding, that is

(4.5)                               p¯ (¯xi ei) = ¯wi + ¯τiγp) + ρp),        i ∈ I

Indeed, suppose that there exists i ∈ I such that

p¯ (¯xi ei) < w¯i + ¯τiγp) + ρp)

That is there exist ξ ∈ D such that

p¯(ξ) •H xi(ξ) − ei(ξ)) < w¯i(ξ) + ¯τiγp)(ξ) + ρp)

But by Claim 4.2, Pi∈Ix¯i = Pi∈Iei and by the nonsatiation assumption C (v) for consumer i, there exists xi Pix) such that xi(ξ0) = ¯xi(ξ0) for every ξ0 6= ξ. Consequently, we can choose x ∈ [xi,x¯i) close enough to x¯i so that(x,w¯i) ∈ Biγρp). But, from the local non-satiation (Assumption K (ii)), [xi,x¯i) ⊂ Pix). Consequently, Biγρp) ∩ (Pix) × WZi) 6= ∅ which contradicts Claim 4.3. This ends the proof of Equation (4.5).

Summing up over i I in the equalities (4.5) and using the market clearing condition (Claim 4.2) we get:

(4.6)                                        0 = Xw¯i + (Xτ¯i)γp) + (#I)ρp)

                                                  i∈I                  i∈I

Taking above the scalar product with λ yields:

0 = λ D (Xw¯i) + (Xτ¯i)λ D γp) + (#I)λ L ρp)

                                               i∈I                    i∈I

But λ D (Pi∈Iw¯i) = 0 since Pi∈Iw¯i ∈ W ⊂ < W >λby Lemma 4.1. Moreover 0 = λ D γp) by Lemma 4.2. Consequently ρ(p) = 0.

Proof of (ii): From Assertion (4.6) and the fact that ρ(p) = 0 we get

(4.7)                                                  Xw¯i = −(Xτ¯i)γp).

                                                      i∈I                      i∈I

Taking the scalar product with Pi∈Iw¯i on both sides and using the fact the closed cone  is linear in Lemma 4.2 we get Pi∈Iw¯i = 0. Again from Assertion

4.7 we get

(Xτ¯i)γp) = 0.

i∈I

Since each τ¯i ≥ 0 we can take the scalar product in the above equation with γp) to conclude that for all i ∈ I¯iγp) = 0.

Proof of (iii): From Assertion 4.7, taking scalar product on both sides with Pi∈Iw¯i on both sides and recalling that τi ∈ [0,1] we get Pi∈Iτ¯i ≤ #I hence

||Xw¯i|| ≤ (#I)||γp)||          i∈I

If closed cone  is a linear space and ei int Xi for all i ∈ I then x,z,¯ p,¯ q¯) is an accounts clearing equilibrium as in Theorem 3.1 as consequence of Claim 4.2, Claim 4.3 and Claim 4.4 (i and ii).

If however, closed cone  is a convex set then we can go to the limit as ε goes to zero and verify that the limit of the sequence will be quasi-weak-equilibrium.

      1. Limit argument when converges to zero and quasi-weak-equilibrium.

Since ei ∈ int Xi, let ε be such that B(ei) ⊂ Xi. Hence there exists a sequence ein

 and eni converges to ei. In the previous section we have associated to

every ε > 0, the list x,w,¯ p¯) and we will now take ε = 1/n and denote the associated list by , to make the dependence on n explicit. Since BL and each of Xi and WZi are compact, without any loss of generality we can assume that the sequence converges to some element (x,¯¯ w,¯¯ p¯¯). Let z¯¯i be such that w¯¯i = Wq)z¯¯i.

We first recall the following sets:

Bi(p,q) = {(xi,zi) ∈ Xi × Zi : p(xi ei) ≤ W(q)zi}.

B˘i(p,q) = {(xi,zi) ∈ Xi × Zi : p(xi ei) << W(q)zi}.

Note that we have

Claim 4.5 (i) γpn) → 0.

  1. ρ(p¯¯) = 0, that is kλ  p¯¯k = 1.
  2. Pi∈Ix¯¯i = Pi∈Iei.
  3. Pi∈IWz¯¯i = 0.

Proof. The first assertion (i) holds since kγpn)k ≤ (#I)/n by Lemma 4.2. The second assertion (ii) comes from the fact that ρ(p¯¯) = limρpn) (by continuity of ρ) and that ρpn) = 0 by Claim 4.4.

Proof of ((iii) and (iv)). From Claim 4.2 we have Pi∈Ix¯ni = Pi∈Ieni and from Claim 4.4 we have ||Pi∈Iw¯ink ≤ (#I)kγpn)k ≤ (#I)1/n. Taking the limit, when n → ∞ we get Assertions (iv) and (v).

In view of the previous Claim 4.5, for (x,¯¯ z,¯¯ p,¯¯ q¯) to be a quasi-weak-equilibrium it only remain to prove that each agent’s preferred set does not intersect the interior of her budget set, that is, the following claims holds true.

Claim 4.6 (i) For all i ∈ I (x¯¯i,z¯¯i) ∈ Bi(p,¯¯ q¯) and B˘i(p,¯¯ q¯) ∩ (Pi(x¯¯) × Zi) = ∅.

(ii) For all ξ ∈ D,xi = (x¯¯i(−ξ),xi(ξ)) ∈ Pi(x¯¯) implies p¯¯(ξ) •H xi(ξ) ≥ p¯¯(ξ) •H x¯¯(ξ).

Proof of (i): To prove the first part, from the fixed-point Condition (4.2), we have xni ,w¯in) ∈ Biγρ,εpn), that is,

xni ,w¯in) ∈ Xi × Wq)Zi and there is ¯τin ∈ [0,1],p¯n  (¯xni eni ) ≤ w¯in + ¯τinγpn) + ρpn).

Taking the limit, when n → ∞, recalling that γpn) → 0 and ρpn) → ρ(p¯¯) = 0, we deduce that (x¯¯i,w¯¯i) ∈ Bi(p¯¯) and (x¯¯i,z¯¯i) ∈ Bi(p,¯¯ q¯).

         We prove the second part by contradiction.                  Assume that there is some (xi,zi) ∈

, then, (xi,zi) ∈ Xi × Zi and p¯¯ (xi ei) << Wq)zi. Then,

recalling that p¯n p¯¯, γpn) → 0 and ρpn) → 0 (from Claim 4.5) for n large enough one has

p¯n  (xi eni ) << Wq)zi + γpn) + ρpn),

that is, (xi,Wq)zi) ∈ B˘iγρpn). Moreover, from the lower semicontinuity of Pi and the fact that Pi has open and convex values, we deduce that, for every xi Xi, the set (Pi)−1 (xi) := {x ∈ Πi∈IXi | xi Pi(x)} is open (in Xi for its relative topology). Therefore for n large enough, xi Pixn) (since, from above, xi Pi(x¯¯) and x¯n x¯¯). Hence, for n large enough, , which is empty from Claim 4.3

(iii). A contradiction.

Proof of (ii): Let xi = (x¯¯i(−ξ),xi(ξ)) ∈ Pi(x¯¯), then for n large enough xin(−ξ),xi(ξ)) ∈ Pixn). We claim that xi Pixn) implies p¯n(ξ) •H xi(ξ) > p¯n(ξ) •H x¯ni (ξ). Suppose not, thenxni (−ξ),xi(ξ)) ∈ Pixn) and p¯n(ξ) •H xi(ξ) ≤ p¯n(ξ) •H x¯ni (ξ). Thus

p¯n  (xi eni ) ≤ p¯n  (¯xinein) ≤ Wqzin + ¯τinγpn).

This contradicts with the optimality of . Thus p¯n(ξ)•Hxi(ξ) > p¯n(ξ)•H x¯ni (ξ). Since we have p¯n and x¯ni converge to p¯¯and x¯¯i respectively, thus in the limit we have p¯¯(ξ) •H xi(ξ) ≥ p¯¯(ξ) •H x¯¯i(ξ).

Thus in view of Claims 4.5 and 4.6 we have (x,¯¯ z,¯¯ p,¯¯ q¯) is a financial accounts clearing quasi-equilibrium.

    1. Proof in the general case (without additional assumptions)

We now give the proof of Theorem 3.1, without considering the additional Assumption

K, as in the previous section. We will first enlarge the strictly preferred sets as in Gale-Mas Colell, and then truncate the economy E by a standard argument to define a new economy Eˆr, which satisfies all the assumptions of E, together with the additional Assumption K. From the previous section, there exists a weak equilibrium of Eˆr and we will then check that it is also a weak equilibrium of E.

      1. Enlarging the preferences as in Gale and Mas-Colell

The original preferences Pi are replaced by the ”enlarged” ones Pˆi defined as follows. For

every i ∈ I, x¯ ∈ Qi∈I Xi we let

Pˆix) := [ xi,xi] = {x¯i + t(xi x¯i) | t ∈]0,1], xi Pix)}.

xiPix)

The next proposition shows that Pˆi satisfies the same properties as Pi, for every i ∈ I, together with the additional Local Nonsatiation Assumption K (ii).

Proposition 4.1 Under (C), for every i ∈ I and every x¯ ∈ Qi∈I Xi one has:

  1. Pix) ⊂ Pˆix) ⊂ Xi;
  2. the correspondence Pˆi is lower semicontinuous at x¯ and Pˆix) is convex;
  3. for every yi Pˆix) for every (x0)i Xi,(x0)i 6= yi then [(x0)i,yi[∩Pˆix) 6= ∅;
  4. x¯i 6∈ Pˆix);
  5. (Non-Satiation at Every Node) if Pi∈I x¯i = PiI ei, for every ξ ∈ D, there exists x

Xi such that, for each ξ0 6= ξ, xi(ξ0) = ¯xi(ξ0) and xi Pˆix); i∈I

(vi) for every yi Pˆix), then [yi,x¯i[⊂ Pˆix).

Proof. Let x¯ ∈ Qi∈I Xi and let i ∈ I.

Part (i). It follows by the convexity of Xi, for every i ∈ I.

Part (ii). Let yi Pˆix) and consider a sequence xn)i Qi∈I Xi converging to x¯. Since yi Pˆix), then yi = ¯xi+t(xix¯i) for some xi Pix) and some t ∈]0,1]. Since Pi is lower semicontinuous, there exists a sequence (xi)converging to xi such that xni Pixn) for every n N. Now define yin := ¯xi + t(xi x¯i) ∈]¯xin,xi]: then yin Pˆixn) and obviously the sequence (yin) converges to yi. This shows that Pˆi is lower semicontinuous at x¯.

To show that Pˆix) is convex, let yi1,yi2 Pˆix), let λ1 ≥ 02 ≥ 0, such that λ1+λ2 = 1, we show that λ1yi1+λ2yi2 Pˆix). Then yik = ¯xi +tk(xki x¯i) for some tk ∈]0,1] and some xki Pix) (k = 1,2). One has

λ1yi1 + λ2yi2 = ¯xi + (λ1t1 + λ2t2)(xi x¯i),

where xi := (λ1t1x1i +λ2t2x2i )/(λ1t1+λ2t2) ∈ Pix) (since Pix) is convex, by Assumption C) and λ1t1 + λ2t2 ∈]0,1]. Hence λ1yi1 + λ2yi2 Pˆix).

Part (iii). Let yi Pˆix) and let (x0)i Xi,(x0)i 6= yi. From the definition of Pˆi, yi = x¯i + t(xi x¯i) for some xi Pix) and some t ∈]0,1]. Suppose first that xi = (x0)i, then yi ∈]¯xi,xi[⊂ Pˆix). Consequently, [(x0)i,yi[∩Pˆix) 6= ∅. Suppose now that xi 6= (x0)i; since Pi satisfies Assumption C (iii), there exists λ ∈ [0,1[ such that xi(λ) = (x0)i+λ(xi−(x0)i) ∈

Pix). We let

z := [λ(1 − txi + t(1 − λ)(x0)i + tλxi]with α := t + λ(1 − t),

and we check that z = [λ(1 − txi + txi(λ)]∈]¯xi,xi(λ)], with xi(λ) ∈ Pix), hence z Pˆix). Moreover, z := [λyi + t(1 − λ)(x0)i]∈ [(x0)i,yi[. Consequently, [(x0)i,yi[∩Pˆix) 6= ∅, which ends the proof of (iii)).

Parts (iv), (v) and (vi). They follow immediately by the definition of Pˆi and the properties satisfied by p in (C).     

      1. Truncating the economy

Given q RJ the set of admissible consumptions and income transfers, K(q) is given by:

K(q) :={(x,w) ∈ Qi∈I Xi × Qi∈I W(q)Zi : ∃p BL(0,1),

(xi,wi) ∈ Bi(p,q) for every i ∈ I, Pi∈Ixi = Pi∈Iei, Pi∈Iwi = 0}.

Lemma 4.3 K(q) is bounded.

Proof of Lemma 4.3: Given q RJ, for every i ∈ I define the following:

                                                                                                                                                                         

Xˆi(q) := xi Xi : ∃(xj)j6=i YXj, w YWZi, (x,w) ∈ K(q)

                                                                                 j6=i                           i∈I                                                  

and

                                                                                                                                                                            

            Wci(q) := wi                                   j                         YWZj, x YXi, (x,w) ∈ K(q).

WZi : ∃(w )j6=i

                                                                                     j6=i                               i∈I                                            

We need to show that Xˆi(q) and are bounded. Since Xˆi is bounded below (by Assumption C (i) clearlyXˆi(q) is bounded.

To show is bounded, let. Since

(xi,wi) ∈ {(x,w) ∈ Xi × W(q)Zi | p  (x ei) ≤ w}

and (xi,p) ∈ Xˆi(q) × BL(0,1), a compact set from above, there exists αi RD, such that

αi p  (xi ei) ≤ wi

Using the fact that Pi∈Iwi = 0 we also have

wi = −Xwj ≤ −Xαj, j6=i     j6=i

Thus is bounded for every i ∈ I.

We now define the ”truncated economy” as follows.

Since Xˆi(q) and Wˆi(q) are bounded subsets of RL and RD, respectively (by Lemma 4.3), there exists a real number r > 0 such that, for every agent i ∈ I, Xˆiq) ⊂ intBL(0,r) and Wˆiq) ⊂ intBD(0,r). The truncated economy  is the collection

,

where,

Xir = Xi BL(0,r), Zir = {z Zi | Wq)z BD(0,r)} and Pˆir(x) = Pˆi(x) ∩ intBL(0,r).

The existence of a weak equilibrium of (Eˆr,Fr) is then a consequence of Section 4.1, that is, Theorem 3.1 with the additional Assumption K. We just have to check that Assumption K and all the assumptions of Theorem 3.1 are satisfied by . In view of Proposition 4.1, this is clearly the case for all the assumptions but the Survival Assumption C (vi) that is proved via a standard argument (that we recall hereafter).

Indeed we first notice that (ei,0)i∈I belongs to K(q), hence, for every i ∈ I, ei Xˆi(q) ⊂ intBL(0,r). Recalling that ei Xi (from the Survival Assumption), we deduce that ei Xi ∩ intBL(0,r) ⊂ [Xi BL(0,r)] = Xir.

Proposition 4.2 Given q¯ ∈ RJ, if x,z,¯ p,¯ q¯) is a weak-equilibrium of  then it is also a weak-equilibrium of (E,F).

Proof of proposition 4.2. Let x,z,¯ p,¯ q¯) be a weak-equilibrium of the economy . In view of the definition of a weak-equilibrium, to prove that it is also a weak-equilibrium of (E,F) we only have to check, for every i ∈ I, [PixZi]∩Bip,q¯) = ∅, where Bip,q¯) denotes the budget set of agent i in the economy (E,F).

Assume, on the contrary, that, for some i ∈ I the set [PixZi]∩Bip,q¯) is nonempty, hence contains a couple (xi,zi). Clearly the allocation x,Wqz) belongs to the set Kq), hence for every i ∈ I, x¯i Xˆiq) ⊂ int BL(0,r) and w¯i = Wqzi Wˆ iq) ⊂ int BD(0,r). Thus, for t ∈]0,1] sufficiently small, xi(t) := ¯xi + t(xi x¯i) ∈ int BL(0,r) and wi(t) := w¯i + t(wi w¯i) ∈ intBD(0,r). Clearly (xi(t),wi(t)) is such that wi(t) = Wq)zi(t) where zi(t) = (¯zi+t(ziz¯i)) ∈ Zi and (xi(t),zi(t)) belongs to the budget set Bip,q¯) of agent i (for the economy (E,F)) and since xi(t) ∈ Xir := XiBL(0,r), zi(t) ∈ Zir := {z Zi | Wq)z BD(0,r)}, the couple (xi(t),zi(t)) belongs also to the budget set Birp,q¯) of agent i (in the economy (Eˆr,Fr)). From the definition of Pˆi, we deduce that xi(t) ∈ Pˆix) (since from above xi(t) := ¯xi + t(xi x¯i) and xi Pix)), hence xi(t) ∈ Pˆirx) := Pˆix) ∩ intBL(0,r). We have thus shown that, for t ∈]0,1] small enough, (xi(t),zi(t)) ∈ [PˆirxZir]∩Birp,q¯).

This contradicts the fact that this set is empty, since x,y,¯ p,¯ q¯) is a weak-equilibrium of the economy (Eˆr,F).

  1. Appendix: Proof of lemma 4.2

Proof of Lemma 4.2: Part (i): We recall that, from Assumption C, there exists r > 0 such that, for all i ∈ I,BL(ei,r) ⊂ Xi, and we define the correspondence Γ from BL to RD by Γ(p) = {γ λ∩ Wo BD(0) | ∃ u BL(0,r),w ∈ W,p  u << w + γ + ρ(p)}.

We will show that there is a continuous selection of Γ, that is, a continuous mapping γ : BL → ∆ such that, for all p BL(p) ∈ Γ(p). This will be deduced from Michael’s theorem (see Prop. 1.5.3 in Florenzano [14]) and we only need to show that for all p BL, (i) Γ(p) is convex, (ii) Γ(p) is nonempty, and (iii) Γ is lower semi-continuous at p.

  1. Γ(p) is convex. To see this, let γ1 ∈ Γ(p) and γ2 ∈ Γ(p), then

1                                     1

1                    1          1

u BL(0,r),w ∈ W : pu << w + γ + ρ(p)

u2 BL(0,r),w2 ∈ W : pu2 << w2 + γ2 + ρ(p)

Then for all α ∈ [0,1],αγ1 + (1 − α)γ2 λ∩ Wo BD(0),αu1 + (1 − α)u2

BL(0,r),αw1 + (1 − α)w2 ∈ W, and

p  (αu1 + (1 − α)u2) << (αw1 + (1 − α)w2) + (αγ1 + (1 − α)γ2) + ρ(p)

Thus αγ1 + (1 − α)γ2 ∈ Γ(p). This shows that Γ(p) is convex.

  1. Γ(p) is nonempty. We will distinguish the two cases ρ(p) 6= 0 and ρ(p) = 0.

If ρ(p) 6= 0, then ||λ p|| < 1. Thus taking u = 0 and w = 0 we see that γ = 0 ∈ Γ(p), since 0 < 0 + ρ(p,ξ) = 1 − ||λ p||, for every ξ ∈ D.

If ρ(p) = 0, i.e., ||λ p|| = 1. Since there exists ξ ∈ D such that p(ξ) 6= 0. Thus there exists u BL(0,r) such that p u < 0. Moreover, there exists t λsuch that

p  u << t; take t = p                 u λD||(λp||2 u)λ (recalling that λ >> 0).

Since W is a closed, convex cone, one has RD = W + Wo (see Rockafellar). Hence, there exists w ∈ W and γ ∈ Wo such that t = w + γ. But w λsince from Lemma 4.1, w ∈ W ⊂ λ. Recalling that t λ, we thus deduce that γ λ. Consequently, for every τ ∈ (0,1]

p  τu << τw + τγ with τu BL(0,r),τw ∈ W and τγ λ∩ Wo

and for τ > 0 small enough, τγ BD(0), which shows that τγ ∈ Γ(p). Thus Γ(p) 6= ∅.

(iii) Γ is lower semicontinuous at p. Let GΓ := {(p,γ) ∈ BL × ∆ | δ ∈ Γ(p)}, denote the graph of Γ. To show that Γ is lower semicontinuous it is sufficient to show that GΓ is open or equivalently that (BL × ∆) \ GΓ is closed. Let {(pkk)} ∈ (BL × ∆) \ GΓ such that (pkk) → (p,δ), we show that (p,δ) ∈/ GΓ by contradiction. Indeed if (p,δ) ∈ GΓ, that is, δ ∈ Γ(p), there exists u¯ ∈ BL(0,r) and w¯ ∈ W such that

(5.1)                             ξ ∈ D,          p(ξ) •H u¯(ξ) << w¯(ξ) + δ(ξ) + ρ(p)

Also for all k,δk / Γ(pk) thus for all u BL(0,r) and for all w ∈ W one has

ξk ∈ D,pk(ξk) •H u(ξk) ≥ w(ξk) + γk(ξk) + ρ(pk)

in particular, there exists ξ¯∈ D such that {k N|ξk = ξ¯} is infinite. Without any loss of generality, by considering a subsequence, we can say that

ξ¯∈ D,pk(ξ¯) •H u¯(ξ¯) ≥ w¯(ξ¯) + δk(ξ¯) + ρ(pk)

Since pk p and δk δ, taking the limit when k → ∞ we get

ξ¯∈ D,p(ξ¯) •H u¯(ξ¯) ≥ w¯(ξ¯) + δ(ξ¯) + ρ(p)

a contradiction with the inequality 5.1. Thus Γ is l.s.c. at p. Moreoveer in the above

we have shown that for all p BL,||γ(p)|| ≤ ε.

Part (ii): Let γ be the continuous selection of Γ obtained in Part (i) above. We want to show that, for every p BL, there exists i ∈ I such that B˘iγρ(p) 6= ∅. To see this, we let p BL and we successively consider the two cases ρ(p) > 0 and ρ(p) = 0.

If ρ(p) > 0, for all i ∈ I, taking τi = 0, we deduce that (xi,wi) = (ei,0) ∈ B˘iγρ(p). If ρ(p) = 0, since γ(p) ∈ Γ(p), there exists u BL(0,r), and w ∈ W such that

p  u << w + γ(p)

By assumption made in the lemma, the closed cone spanned by Wq)(∪IIZi) is convex, hence W = cl cone Wq)(∪IIZi) and w = limtnvn for some sequence (tn) ⊂ R+ and (vn) ⊂ Wq)(∪IIZi). Without any loss of generality (by eventually considering a sequence) we can assume that vn = win belongs to some given set Wq)Zi (for some given i independent of n).

Suppose first that w = 0, then clearly (ei + u,0) ∈ B˘iγρ(p) for all i ∈ I.

Suppose now that w 6= 0, then without any loss of generality (by eventually considering a subsequence) we can assume that tn > 0 for every n. From the above inequality, recalling that w = limtnwin we have p  u << tnwin + γ(p) for n large enough.

Then for τ > 0 small enough (τ ≤ 1 and τ tn) we have

                                      τ                          n         τ

p        n u) << τwi + n γ(p)      with t    t

Moreover τwin Wq)Zi since 0 ∈ Wq)Zi (and 0 ≤ τ ≤ 1).

This shows that, for n large enough, .

References

  1. L. Angeloni and B. Cornet, Existence of financial equilibria in a multi-period stochastic economy, Advances in Mathematical Economics, 8 (2006), 1-31.
  2. Y. Balasko, D. Cass and P. Siconolfi, The structure of financial equilibrium with endogenous yields, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 19 (1990), 195216.
  3. L. Benveniste and H. Ketterer, Arbitrage opportunities in financial markets are not inconsistent with competitive equilibrium, in Madumdar, eds., Equilibrium and Dynamics: Essays in honor of David Gale. New York: St. Martin’s Press (1992).
  4. D. Cass, Competitive equilibrium in incomplete financial markets, CARESS Working Paper No.3 (1984), University of Pennsylvania.
  5. D. Cass, Competitive equilibrium with incomplete financial markets, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 42 (2006), 384-405.
  6. D. Cass, P. Siconolfi and A. Villanacci, Generic regularity of competitive equilibriua with restricted participation, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 36 (2001), 61-76.
  7. B. Cornet and R. Gopalan, Restricted participation and arbitrage in a multiperiod model, University of Kansas Working Paper, (2006).
  8. V. Martins Da-Rocha and L. Triki, Equilibria in exchange economies with financial constraints: beyond the Cass trick, CERMSEM Working Paper,

(2005).

  1. G. Debreu, Theory of value, Wiley (1959).
  2. D. Duffie, Stochastic equilibria with incomplete financial markets, Journal of Economic Theory, 41 (1987), 404-416.
  3. D. Duffie and W. Shafer, Equilibrium in incomplete markets: I. A basic model of generic existence in Stochastic Economies, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 14 (1985), 285-300.
  4. H. Elsinger and M. Summer, Arbitrage and Optimal Portfolio Choice with Financial Constraints, Austrian Central Bank Working Paper, 49 (2001).
  5. M. Florenzano and P. Gourdel, T-period economies with incomplete markets, Economic Letters, 44 (1994), 91-97.
  6. M. Florenzano, General equilibrium analysis: Existence and optimality properties of equilibria, Kluwer Academic Publishers, (2003).
  7. D. Gale and A. Mas Colell,: An equilibrium existence theorem for a general model without ordered preferences, Journal of Mathematical Economics., 2 (1975), 9-15.
  8. J. Geanakoplos and H. Polemarchakis, Existence, regularity and constrainted suboptimality of competitive allocations when the asset market is incomplete, in Uncertainty, information and communication: Essays in honor of Kenneth J Arrow, Vlo. III, (Heller et al. Ed.), Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK (1986).
  9. J. Geanakoplos and W. Shafer, Solving systems of simultaneous equations in economics, Journal of Financial Economics, 19 (1990), 69-93.
  10. T. Hens, P. Jean-Jacques Herings and A. Predtetchinskii, Limits to arbitrage when market participation is restricted, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 42, 42 (2006), 556-564.
  11. M. Magill and W. Shafer, Incomplete Markets, Handbook of Mathematical Economics, Vol. 4 (K. Arrow and M. Intriligator, eds.) Amsterdam: NorthHolland, (1991).
  12. M. Magill and M. Quinzii, Theory of incomplete markets, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA (1996).
  13. G. Hahn and D. Won, Arbitrage pricing and the existence f equilibrium under portfolo constraints, Working Paper Series, Kongju National University (2003).
  14. M. Hirsch, M. Magill, and A. Mas Colell,: A geometric approach to the class of equilibrium existence theorems, Journal of Mathematical Economics., 19 (1990), 95-106.
  15. H. Polemarchakis and P. Siconolfi, Generic Existence of competitive equilibria with restricted participation, Journal of Mathematical Economics., 28 (1997), 289-311.
  16. R. Radner, Existence of equilibrium plans, prices, and price expectations , Econometrica, 40 (1972), 289-303.
  17. R. Radner and M. Rothschild, On the Allocation of Effort, Journal of Economic Theory, 10 (1975), 358-376.
  18. A. Seghir and L. Triki, On the survival and irreducibility assumptions for financial markets with nominal assets, cahiers de la Maison des sciences Economiques, Universite Panth´ eon Sorbonne (Paris 1), 2004.´
  19. P. Siconolfi, Equilibrium with asymmetric constraints on portfolio holdings and incomplete financial markets, CARESS Working Paper (1986), University of Pennsylvania.
  20. A. Villanacci, L. Carosi, P. Beneveri and A. Battinelli, Differential Topology and general equilibrium with incomplete markets, Kluwer Academic Publishers (2002)
  21. J. Werner, Equilibrium in economies with incomplete financial markets, Journal of Economic Theory, 36 (1985), 110-119.
  22. J. Werner, Equilibrium with incomplete markets without ordered preferences, Journal of Economic Theory, 49 (1989), 379-382.

[1] In this paper, we shall use the following notations. A (D × J)−matrix A is an element of RD×J, with entries (a(ξ,j))ξD,jJ; we denote by A(ξ) ∈ RJ the ξth row of A and by A(j) ∈ RD the jth column of A.We recall that the transpose of A is the unique (J × D)−matrix tA satisfying (Ax) •D y = x J (tAy), for every x RJ, y RD, where D [resp. J] denotes the usual scalar product in RD [resp. RJ]. We shall denote by rankA the rank of the matrix A. For every subsets De ⊂ D and eJ J, the (De × eJ)−sub-matrix of A is the (De × eJ)−matrix Ae with entries ea(ξ,j) = a(ξ,j) for every (ξ,j) ∈ De × eJ. Let x,y be in Rn; we shall use the notation x y (resp.  (resp.) for every h = 1,...,n and we let

. We shall also use the notation x > y if x y and

x 6= y. We shall denote by k · k the Euclidean norm in the different Euclidean spaces used in this paper and the closed ball centered at x RL of radius r > 0 is denoted BL(x,r) := {y RL : ky xk ≤ r}.

[2] Given a subset A Rn we denote hAi := Span A.

[3] A correspondence ϕ : X −→ Y is said to be lower semicontinuous at x0 X if, for every open set V Y such that V ϕ(x0) is not empty, there exists a neighborhood U of x0 in X such that, for all x U, V ϕ(x) is nonempty. The correspondence ϕ is said to be lower semicontinuous if it is lower semicontinuous at each point of X.

[4] Given a convex set Y Rn, the asymptotic cone of Y is A(Y ) := {t Rn | y + t Y, y Y }.